首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   2123篇
  免费   133篇
  国内免费   73篇
测绘学   64篇
大气科学   93篇
地球物理   110篇
地质学   328篇
海洋学   111篇
天文学   2篇
综合类   160篇
自然地理   1461篇
  2023年   15篇
  2022年   74篇
  2021年   78篇
  2020年   89篇
  2019年   88篇
  2018年   78篇
  2017年   93篇
  2016年   96篇
  2015年   86篇
  2014年   84篇
  2013年   137篇
  2012年   111篇
  2011年   99篇
  2010年   81篇
  2009年   85篇
  2008年   90篇
  2007年   97篇
  2006年   85篇
  2005年   80篇
  2004年   87篇
  2003年   80篇
  2002年   77篇
  2001年   68篇
  2000年   69篇
  1999年   45篇
  1998年   58篇
  1997年   46篇
  1996年   27篇
  1995年   22篇
  1994年   25篇
  1993年   10篇
  1992年   14篇
  1991年   15篇
  1990年   4篇
  1989年   6篇
  1988年   3篇
  1987年   6篇
  1986年   4篇
  1985年   6篇
  1984年   4篇
  1983年   1篇
  1982年   2篇
  1977年   1篇
  1976年   1篇
  1975年   1篇
  1974年   1篇
排序方式: 共有2329条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
991.
Climate mitigation credits have mobilized considerable resources for projects in developing countries, but similar funding to adapt to climate change has yet to emerge. The Copenhagen Accord targets up to US$50 billion per year in adaptation funding, but commitments to date have been trivial compared to what is needed. Although there are some studies and suggestions, it remains unclear where the money will come from and how it will be disbursed. Beyond this, many development experts believe that the main hurdle in climate adaptation is effective implementation. A framework, based on the polluter pays principle, is presented here regarding the mobilization of resources for adaptation in developing countries using market mechanisms. It is assumed that mitigation and adaptation are at least partly fungible in terms of long-term global societal costs and benefits, and that quantifying climate vulnerability reductions is possible at least sometimes. The scheme's benefits include significant, equitable and flexible capital flows, and improved and more efficient resource allocation and verification procedures that incentivize sustained project management. Challenges include overcoming political resistance to historical responsibility-based obligations and scepticism of market instruments, and, critically, quantifying climate impact costs and verifying investments for vulnerability reduction credits.  相似文献   
992.
A carbon tax will form the central carbon pricing instrument in South Africa. The country, however, is also in the process of setting specific short-term emissions limits at a subnational level. Additional mitigation policy instruments will thus be required to meet these targets. Although it is possible to combine sector-level quantity targets with a broad-based carbon tax, this article finds that this greatly complicates mitigation policy design, increasing both the information requirements and the likelihood of unintended consequences. The trade-offs between economic efficiency (optimized by the use of a broad-based price set by a carbon tax) and environmental effectiveness (optimized by using instruments that ensure emissions reduction targets are met) are ever present. A clear understanding of subnational quantity targets and an appreciation of the characteristics of the instruments to achieve such targets (quantity-based instruments, QBIs), the framework through which the instruments are combined, and their possible interactions, are required for effective policy making. Three possible frameworks for combining instruments are identified in the article, and some specific implications of interaction between particular QBIs and a carbon tax are suggested.

Policy relevance

This article explores the interaction of a carbon tax with mitigation policy instruments to meet subnational emissions targets in the South African context (where both a carbon tax and subnational emissions targets are currently being developed). As international negotiations progress towards countries accepting binding GHG emissions restrictions, quantity-based mitigation policy approaches become more important. In countries where a broad-based emissions trading scheme (ETS) is not feasible in the short to medium term, combining a broad-based carbon tax with subnational emission targets provides an alternative mechanism for achieving the economic efficiency and emissions certainty benefits derived from an ETS. This paper considers the mechanisms through which such a combination of instruments can be achieved. Three possible frameworks for combining instruments are identified, some specific implications of interaction between particular QBIs and a carbon tax are suggested, and guidelines and concept tools are presented to assist policy-makers in designing efficient and coherent mitigation policy.  相似文献   
993.
Passenger vehicles and power plants are major sources of GHG emissions. While economic analyses generally indicate that a broader market-based approach to GHG reduction would be less costly and more effective, regulatory approaches have found greater political success. We evaluate a global regulatory regime that replaces coal with natural gas in the electricity sector and imposes technically achievable improvements in the efficiency of personal transport vehicles. Its performance and cost are compared with other scenarios of future policy development including a no-policy world, achievements under the Copenhagen Accord, and a price-based policy to reduce global emissions by 50% by 2050. The assumed regulations applied globally achieve a global emissions reduction larger than projected for the Copenhagen agreements, but they do not prevent global GHG emissions from continuing to grow. The reduction in emissions is achieved at a high cost compared to a price-based policy. Diagnosis of the reasons for the limited yet high-cost performance reveals influences including the partial coverage of emitting sectors, small or no influence on the demand for emissions-intensive products, leakage when a reduction in fossil use in the covered sectors lowers the price to others, and the partial coverage of GHGs. If these regulatory measures are in part correcting other barriers or behavioural limitations consumers face, the benefits of overcoming these could offset at least some of the costs we estimate. The extent of any efficiency gap – the difference between engineering estimates of best practice and what actually happens – is highly contested, and offers an important avenue for future research.

Policy relevance

While analysts concerned with national cost of GHG control have long advocated a GHG pricing policy, by a cap-and-trade system or a tax, covering all emissions sources and gases, governments more often pursue sectoral policies and technology standards. Given these political realities, the regulations represent a more politically practical approach to GHG reductions, focusing on solutions that are within reach and that do not depend on technological breakthroughs. If regulations are imposed as a way to get started on larger emissions reductions, and then combined with a broader GHG pricing policy pursuing a deep global cut in emissions, its requirements will eventually be overtaken by the pricing policy. The remaining higher costs of the regulatory targets become diluted so that in later years the difference in average cost per ton between a least-cost approach and one preceded by a period of regulatory action becomes very small.  相似文献   
994.
Book review     
《Climate Policy》2013,13(4):395-396
In 2007 the US Congress began considering a set of bills to implement a cap-and-trade system to limit the nation's greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions. The MIT Integrated Global System Model (IGSM)—and its economic component, the Emissions Prediction and Policy Analysis (EPPA) model—were used to assess these proposals. In the absence of policy, the EPPA model projects a doubling of US greenhouse gas emissions by 2050. Global emissions, driven by growth in developing countries, are projected to increase even more. Unrestrained, these emissions would lead to an increase in global CO2 concentration from a current level of 380 ppmv to about 550 ppmv by 2050 and to near 900 ppmv by 2100, resulting in a year 2100 global temperature 3.5–4.5°C above the current level. The more ambitious of the Congressional proposals could limit this increase to around 2°C, but only if other nations, including developing countries, also strongly controlled greenhouse gas emissions. With these more aggressive reductions, the economic cost measured in terms of changes in total welfare in the United States could range from 1.5% to almost 2% by the 2040–2050 period, with 2015 CO2-equivalent prices between $30 and $55, rising to between $120 and $210 by 2050. This level of cost would not seriously affect US GDP growth but would imply large-scale changes in its energy system.  相似文献   
995.
地热水既是一种宝贵的自然资源,又具有典型的稀有性和难以再生性.在大力提倡低碳经济,节能减排,积极应对全球气候变暖的今天,既要利用地热水资源,又要重视地热水资源的可持续性.西安市的地热资源得天独厚,具有分布广,储量大,温度高,水量丰,水压大,水质优等显著特点.是大自然馈赠西安人民的十分珍贵的清洁能源.用得好,可为西安人们...  相似文献   
996.
生态经济研究中的整体性视角   总被引:16,自引:15,他引:1  
徐中民  程国栋 《冰川冻土》2011,33(3):668-675
在简要介绍整体性视角含义的基础上,总结了生态经济学基本思想、主要问题、学科演替、新兴领域及未来研究主题中体现的整体性视角.分析了传统的水资源社会经济循环规律研究的劣势,在简单介绍了上升性(效率)、发展能力、恢复力和可持续性等指标及其含义后,开发了整体性视角下的水资源社会经济循环规律研究框架.最后系统地总结了整体性视角在...  相似文献   
997.
甘肃省各地区相对资源承载力及可持续发展研究   总被引:1,自引:1,他引:0  
李丽娟  张勃 《冰川冻土》2011,33(5):1169-1175
根据相对资源承载力研究方法,以全国及甘肃省为参照区域,计算了2001—2008年甘肃省各地区相对自然资源承载力、相对经济资源承载力和综合资源承载力.结果表明:甘肃省的承载状态在2001—2002年呈超载状态,但自2003年以后处于富余状态;甘肃省超载最严重的是临夏,其次是陇南,然后依次是天水、甘南、定西、武威.省会兰州...  相似文献   
998.
近年来,烟台经济开发区重视土地储备工作,从完善规章制度入手,对土地储备工作运行机制进行了规范。加强了土地资源的优化配置,实现了土地收益的最大化,有力的支持了当地经济的发展。但仍存在着一些不容忽视的问题,针对存在的问题进行了分析、探讨,并提出相应的对策建议。  相似文献   
999.
从山东半岛蓝色经济区的区位优势、经济发展背景方面阐述了开展山东半岛蓝色经济区矿产资源规划的作用和意义,提出了山东半岛蓝色经济区矿产资源规划总体思路、发展目标及政策措施,对区内的矿产资源勘查、开发利用与保护具有指导意义。  相似文献   
1000.
油页岩资源开发利用经济评价   总被引:3,自引:1,他引:2  
油页岩资源是一种重要的非常规油气资源,但是,其作为单独的一种产品开发利用具有很大的局限性,所以,油页岩资源的开发利用必须走综合利用的途径.这就要求油页岩资源开发利用项目的经济评价应当采用产业经济模式评价,而不能采用行业经济模式评价.通过调研分析,建立产业经济模式评价模型,按产能比模拟年产5x10<'4>t页岩油的"油页...  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号